Failed Regulation in the Credit Rating Industry?
This post reviews a recent article in the Wall Street Journal, written by Cezary
Podkul and Gunjan Banerji, entitled Inflated
Bond Ratings Helped Spur the Financial Crisis. They’re Back. Regular readers
will know that the credit rating agencies and their performances over the past
two decades have been reviewed extensively and critically here in Financial Regulation Matters on account
of the author’s specialism. However, whilst there has been repeated criticism
of the agencies themselves, the regulators and their post-Crisis attempts to
constrain the industry deserve more attention. The WSJ article suggests that
post-Crisis regulatory endeavours have failed and this falls in line with a
thesis of this author who has suggested that regulators
are regulating imagined, or idealised entities rather than the agencies and the
industry as it actually exists. Therefore, we will review the article and
ask what its findings mean for post-Crisis regulation in the credit rating
arena.
The fascinating article begins by declaring that ‘inflated
bond ratings were once cause of the financial crisis. A decade later, there is
evidence they persist’. It is claimed that all of the top 6 firms have, since
2012, adjusted their rating methodologies which then went on to result in an
increase in their market share. This has been centred upon the structured
finance market according to the article, with the authors researching more than
30,000 ratings within a $3 trillion database from the established Big Three
(S&P, Moody’s, and Fitch) and the three agencies that have emerged/been
encouraged to challenge them since the crisis (DBRS, Kroll Bond Rating Agency,
and Morningstar) – we reviewed the acquisition of DBRS by Morningstar recently here.
The results of this research suggest, as the article states, that ‘a key
regulatory remedy to improve rating quality – promoting competition – has backfired’.
This is because the ‘Small Three’, as I will call them here, tended to rate
bonds and structured finance products even
higher than the Big Three did – the article suggests that on occasion the
divergence between the two sets of ratings would be as wide as one being deemed
‘junk’ and the other being deemed AAA, which is a remarkable deviation on the
same bond/product. This issue of rating inflation has been found by a number of
researchers to exist, almost fundamentally, within the credit rating industry
and this WSJ article suggests even further that it is perhaps an inherent
characteristic of a credit rating agency (irrespective of whether the agency is
an oligopolistic member or not). The influential Professor Bo Becker studied
S&P in 2011 when they were shut out of the commercial mortgage-backed
securities (CMBS) market and found that, once they could rate in that market
again, S&P provided higher ratings than any of its competitors, which lead
Becker to argue that this was done in
the name of market share. Studies on this topic stretch back to the implementation
of the ‘issuer-pays’ model with research from Jiang et al confirming that, when
Moody’s incorporated the model and S&P did not, Moody’s ratings were higher
– when S&P incorporated the model themselves 3/4 years later, parity
was resumed at the higher level between the two rating giants.
The article goes on to cite senior credit analysts from
Fitch who suggest that ‘I suppose that’s the flip side, isn’t it, of having
more competition among rating agencies’ – the analyst is speaking about the
article’s findings that DBRS rated a certain hotel deal as up to two rungs
higher than Morningstar because it had just loosened its rating criteria (its
then-competitor) and, as a result, its market share jumped by 26%. There is a
further issue cited whereby a number of investors urged S&P to not loosen
their rating criteria through a fear that changes would lead to a ‘weakening of
credit protection for investors at a time where we need it most’ – S&P apparently
rejected this call. This led former S&P employee David Jacob to argue that
any loss in market share was attributed to harsher rating methodologies and
those methodologies were, and continue to be altered accordingly. What is
happening now, according to the article, is that the Small Three are attempting
to make up for the massive chasm in market share between them and the Big Three
by inflating their ratings excessively – DBRS is cited as rating CMBS bonds 39%
(S&P), 21% (Moody’s), and 30% (Fitch) higher than its larger competitors
(Morningstar and Kroll are apparently no better).
However, the Small Three have responded. Morningstar argued
that there is bias in the data analysed by the WSJ because when the Small Three
provide more conservative feedback to the issuers, they are often not selected
as a result – Morningstar argue that if all of these (then) unpublished ratings
were taken into account, then the picture would look very different. Fitch
argue that rating diversity is good for investors and that they can take their
investment decisions accordingly based upon the variety of ratings available to
them. These defences raise a number of important questions which are worth
considering.
First, the situation is different for the Small Three, and
this needs to be remembered. There is a tendency in the literature (and this
article in particular) to consider that all rating agencies are equal – they are
not. The pressures on the Small Three are much more acute, and the relationship
they have between themselves and the issuers are very different. The issuers
have much more leverage, and also it is the case that just through sheer rating
volume, unpublished ratings will skew the data set for any such analysis. We
can see that the pressures are different with the Small Three as they have had
to devour each other, in some sense, to stay alive. The DBRS deal is necessary at the lower end of the
market, whilst the Big Three enjoy unrivalled oligopolistic status.
The second question this article raises is to do with
regulatory efficiency. The article states that the regulatory action taken in
the aftermath of the Crisis has ‘backfired’, but I would argue that the correct
term is that is has failed. Any
onlooker would have been able to see that the rating industry is not primed for
increased competition by its very nature – the rating agencies in the oligopoly
certainly do not want it, the issuers do not want it for the most part, and it
will (and has) led to increased confusion and complexity for investors. I wrote
about the EU’s attempts to do this in 2017 here and
we spoke
recently of how the EU is starting to admit that this policy is not
working. The reality is as I suggested in my book Regulation
and the Credit Rating Agencies – there is a massive divergence between
the actual and the desired. Regulators and legislators
wanted to be seen to be acting in the aftermath of the Crisis, irrespective of
the validity of their actions. I argued after the $864 million fine given to
Moody’s for its Crisis-era conduct that, for the regulators/legislators, their work
was done. However, this is simply not the case and the market is now being
burdened by those regulatory actions. The WSJ article cites Becker who states
that reliance upon the agencies has gone from ‘high to higher’, despite the
aims of the Dodd-Frank and three EU regulations that aimed to destroy that
reliance by removal of references within regulation/legislation – Becker found
that 94% of rules governing investments ‘made direct or indirect references to
ratings in 2017, versus 90% in 2010’. Simply put, this is yet another example
of reactive regulating/legislating.
So, what is the solution? That is the ‘million dollar
question’ although, in reality, it is worth much more than that. One element
that needs to be considered more is the role of investors. Regulators have
failed in their quest to positively affect the industry. If we look at the
agencies’ collective commitment to ESG principles recently – although we must
be particularly cautious when attributing praise in this area just yet – it is
clear to see that investor pressure is
particularly potent. I discussed this in my book The Role of
Credit Rating Agencies in Responsible Finance and it is unquestionable
that action, linked to the agencies’ quest for profits, is the most affectual
approach that is currently available. If there is a potential to make a lot of
money, or a potential that investors will reduce their need for the ratings,
then rating agency action will follow immediately afterwards. At the moment the
lure of a new marketplace (sustainable finance) is partly determining agency
performance and behaviour. The next stage of academic and professional insight
must be how professional investors utilise market data for their investment
needs. If it is found that, actually, credit ratings are useful to the process
(although many esteemed scholars, such as Professor Frank Partnoy, have argued
that they are not useful in this sense), then examining ways in which
shareholders can institute pressure will be useful to the development to the
marketplace. As for regulators, it is vital that they regroup and consider the benefit
of reactive regulation. However, the more one thinks of it, it is perhaps
legislators who need to develop the most. The thought of, say, the US
legislature enacting impactful and potentially constraining reform within a
bull market is seemingly unthinkable, and perhaps therein lies the issue –
cyclicity in the marketplace tends to have only one consequence… more
cyclicity.
Keywords – credit rating agencies, WSJ, rating inflation, @finregmatters
Comments
Post a Comment