Barclays and the Too-Big-to-Jail Myth
We have examined Barclays on a number of occasions here in Financial Regulation Matters, with a
number of posts focusing on the Bank’s
dealings with Qatar at the height of the Crisis. The approach taken by
Barclays – to deal with Qatar for emergency funding during the height of the
Crisis rather than seek Governmental support – has been the subject of a number
of investigations since and has brought a number of regulatory bodies into the
picture. In today’s post we will examine the interconnecting dynamic that
exists between a number of British regulators and the economic, political, and
societal factors that affect their ability to effectively regulate. We will not
revisit the developments between Barclays and Qatar in any great detail here,
as it has been covered before in
the blog and by the business
media. Rather, we will focus on developments detailed in today’s business
press that suggest that the Bank of England, via its Prudential
Regulation Authority body, argued to prosecutors at the Serious Fraud
Office that criminal charges brought against the Bank ‘could
destabilise Barclays’.
The obvious question to ask on the back of this news is
whether intervening in such a manner is appropriate. A number of prominent onlookers
(including Professors Prem Sikka
and Emilios Avgouleas) have
commented today that today’s revelations demonstrate regulatory
ineffectiveness, ultimately suggesting that such dynamics only serve to
continue such destructive practices (referring to too-big-to-jail). According
to the Financial Times, the BoE’s top
banking supervisor spoke with David Green, the then-Director of the SFO, and
warned that a criminal prosecution would result in ‘unpredictable
consequences’ for the bank and, therefore, the sector. It is important to
note that the source of this revelation has not been identified and that all
parties concerned are refusing to comment as of yet, but the implications are
extraordinary. The Financial Times
continue by making the point that Barclays was charged by
the SFO anyway, with there being very little effect to the position of the
Bank as a result. This then brings into question the concept of using fear to
lobby on the behalf of the regulated entities.
Admittedly, that concept sounds conspiratorial. The official
understanding of the concept is much more subtle, with then-Deputy of the Bank
of England Andrew Bailey – now in charge of
the Financial Conduct Authority – explaining in 2014 that regulators around
the world (meaning US regulators mainly) need to put their ‘cards on
the table’ before penalising regulated entities so as not to cause systemic
risks. This was the reasoning behind George Osborne, then-Chancellor of the
Exchequer, writing to the US Federal Reserve to ‘express
concern’ over the impact of charges against British-based Banks like HSBC. There
are perhaps two schools of thought in this instance. One may suggest that
regulators need to be concerned with systemic issues to avoid a repeat of the
Financial Crisis and are justified, therefore, in considering the impact of
large penalties against important entities within a given sector. This makes
sense. However, there is an issue with the application
of that approach.
If we consider the actions of the FCA regarding the release
of an investigative report into the conduct of RBS (a majoritively state-owned
Bank), then the intervention of the regulator to stop
the publication of that report takes on a different meaning in light of
today’s suggestions. The implications of understanding decisions from within
this too-big-to-jail lens means that systemically-important financial entities
can transgress without damaging consequences. Regulators, wary of systemic
repercussions, will intervene on the
regulated entities’ behalf. Whilst the case of Barclays may not necessarily be
directly applicable, it is telling that there was very little effect to its
position as a result of the prosecution (which has since been scrubbed). In
reality, RBS has continued on pace through the GRG scandal. HSBC is surviving
just fine irrespective of massive fines. There is enough evidence to suggest
that penalties can be exacted (let us just stick with financial penalties for
the time being) without there being a systemic risk. If we accept that to be
true, then a reality comes to light which is a difficult one to accept,
perhaps. That reality is that financial regulators protect the regulated
entities, not the victims of their crimes. The rationale for that position is
complicated however. Who is to say what the dominating factor is in a regulator’s
decision-making process, but the pattern is certainly one of perpetrator-first,
rather than victim-first. Perhaps, the rationale is irrelevant. The impact
remains the same, and that impact permeates the economic cycle so that in good
times the perpetrator is prioritised, and in bad times the perpetrator is
prioritised. Perhaps that is a systemic reality that explains the majority of
decisions that take place – the system is the most important aspect. That
understanding fundamentally changes the concept of ‘systemic importance’.
Keywords – financial regulation; banking; UK; Business; @finregmatters
Comments
Post a Comment