The SEC Receives Renewed Calls for Credit Rating Industry Reform, but Will it Act?

There have been a number of developments recently with regards to the Securities and Exchange Commission receiving advice on how best to regulate the credit rating industry. Last month, a panel was convened so that the Investor Advisory Committee could hear from a number of experts on some of the issues facing the industry, and some potential solutions. Then, at the beginning of this month, the Credit Ratings Subcommittee of the Fixed Income Market Structure Advisory Committee (FIMSAC) produced a recommendation outlining three key areas for regulatory development. In light of this, this post will review the developments, and also examine whether the calls are realistic, or whether they may spurn the SEC into more action in this area.

 

The meeting of the SEC’s Investor Advisory Committee took place on the 21st May, virtually – recording available here. In the afternoon, a panel was convened that was made up of: Professor Frank Partnoy of the University of California, Berkeley; Marc Joffe of the Reason Foundation, Yann Le Pallec who is the Head of Global Rating Services at S&P; Van Hesser who is the Chief Strategist for Kroll Bond Rating Agency; and Professor Joe Grundfest of Stanford University. Van Hesser addressed the Committee first, noting that increased business in the past few years indicates that KBRA is progressing in the market. The point was made that KBRA aimed to offer a differentiated experience for the industry in the wake of the Crisis, and that this recent and consistent upturn in their fortunes was an indication of that model being accepted by the marketplace. In discussing the pandemic, Van Hesser mentioned how there are a wide range of factors that affect credit ratings, and that the current situation is very fluid and, in many ways, unprecedented.

 

Professor Frank Partnoy then followed with a succinct overview of the industry’s regulation and some of the issues that have emerged since the Crisis. One of which was the fact that, despite some successes, a number of regulatory initiatives have failed. One such failure is with regards to the attempted to reduce ‘regulatory reliance’, which is based on a concept Partnoy developed known as the ‘regulatory licence’. Partnoy noted how a number of pieces of legislation, and ensuing regulation that dictated that references to ratings should be entirely removed, simply have not been implemented. This is on top of the behavioural difficulties in removing reliance on the ratings. As potential solutions to such issues, Partnoy suggests a number of approaches. First, he suggests that financial entities, such as banks, should have to disclose what they are holding if they are using rated investments, and preferably on a granular level. Also, as he has long since championed, a number of other more market-based approaches to understanding creditworthiness should be utilised by the market. He then turned his attention to the way in which the SEC actually provides details of its investigations and examinations. A point of issue has been that the SEC will not ‘name names’ when it comes to providing information on who it has found to be transgressing – it will often say things like ‘we found that a mid-sized agency did not…’, which Partnoy suggests affects the regulatory capital in this area; he argues that there is a benefit in the market knowing who has been found to be falling below the standards set. Finally, he discusses the issues with regards to aspects such as the protection being afforded to the agencies via the exemption of the application of Section 11, which was repealed in the wake of the Crisis to expose the agencies to liability, something which has never taken hold.

 

Marc Joffe then followed, and addressed issues regarding the negative effects of increased competition i.e. increased rates of ‘ratings shopping’. He followed this with a discussion around higher CMBS ratings, which appear to be inconsistent with the push by the Dodd-Frank Act to implement ‘universal ratings’ which would increase transparency and clarity in the area. Joffe then produced a number of interesting proposals, including insightful declarations of the alternatives to credit ratings that exist within the marketplace (he cited analytics firms/ regulator-developed methodologies/ the incorporation of Universities [he cited the work at the NUS in Singapore] and non-profits/ and open-sourced methodologies) as well as a number of distinct policy recommendations. Those included avoiding the use of NRSROs in standards, eliminating the concept of NRSROs altogether, enforcing the 17g-5 program better, and potentially incorporating machine-readable financial disclosures into the financial system more.

 

Following on from Joffe, S&P’s Yann Le Pallec introduced the viewpoint of one of the ‘Big Two’, and discussed a number of elements and initiatives that S&P have undertook. He mentioned how S&P have invested heavily in a number of safeguards to prevent, or at least reduce the impact of a number of recognised conflicts of interest. This was adjoined to the interesting point that the company deals with more than 20 regulators worldwide, perhaps hinting at the need for more joined-up regulatory thinking. He then detailed how S&P has invested heavily in its compliance functions, although this has been noted in the literature (not just related to S&P) as being a negative outcome of the regulatory era i.e. simply moving to a tick-box culture as opposed to focusing on the underlying causes of such failures. In addition to this, Le Pallec discussed how new training initiatives and standards have been developed. To address some of the more obvious criticisms of the rating industry, he concluded by discussing how both S&P has long since supported the reduction of regulatory reliance, and that every remuneration model in the rating industry comes with conflicts and that, ultimately, the responsibility lies with the investor to utilise the information they have available to them responsibly.

 

Professor Grundfest then followed, with the initial part of his segment addressing the view that the stable duopoly in the sector produces very little innovation. He then clarified that, in his view, the issuer-pays remuneration model is the only realistic model for agencies who are the largest in the industry. He then discussed an idea that he has championed. This is the ‘Buyer-owned and Controlled Rating Agency’, or BOCRA. Essentially, the idea is that these entities would be owned and operated by some of the larger investors, with the concept being that the entity would have ‘strong incentives to promote an investor’s point of view in the rating process’. The financial support for such entities would be gained from a partnering arrangement whereby every time an issuer pays for an NRSRO’s rating, they would have to pay for a rating from a BOCRA. Grundfest suggests that there would be no limit on the amount of BOCRAs, but that in reality only two would likely emerge and that the market would dictate its prices. This approach contains many more details - available in the link above – but Grundfest did begin with acknowledging that it is slightly ‘controversial’.

 

The section concluded with some interesting Q&As, with one in particular (from JW Verret of George Mason University) raising the issue of the Office of Credit Ratings being particularly underfunded in relation to other bodies in other industries that have similar mandates (like PCAOB).

 

Then, on June 1st, the Credit Ratings Subcommittee of FIMSAC announced that it was recommending a number of proposals with regards to the regulatory needs within the rating sphere. In its recommendations, that were based on a number of months of research and testimony, the subcommittee focused on three elements in particular: the need for increased NRSRO disclosure; the need for enhanced levels of issuer disclosure; and a mechanism for bondholders to vote on the issuer-selected NRSROs.

 

On the first point, the recommendation is that NRSROs should provide more in-depth information about their models and how the models differ by industry. Furthermore, if there are any inputs that effect a model, for example any qualitative inputs, then these should also be declared publicly. With regards to deviations from stated methodologies – which is not allowed unless expressly declared and with good reason – the subcommittee suggests that additional summary statistics on how often, and to what extent NRSROs have deviated would be useful for further research.

 

With regards to increased disclosure from issuers, the subcommittee first finds that for corporate issuers, the process of how NRSROs are selected should be more transparent, and to this end they suggest that the SEC should work alongside trade groups so that ‘best practice’ in this area can be identified and replicated. For securitised issuers, the same selection process is of interest to the committee, with it suggesting that more transparency is needed. In addition to a similar establishment of ‘best practices’ in this area, the subcommittee also suggests that any time a rating agency is selected but the rating not subsequently published, then this should be made public so that investors can be aware of any potential instances of ‘rating shopping’.

 

Finally, in relation to the bondholders voting on the selection of NRSROs, the subcommittee suggests that, like public auditors, the bondholders should be able to vote on whether to ratify, or simply to confirm confidence in the NRSRO selected to develop the rating for the bond. The subcommittee argues that this may provide for additional discipline on the rating agencies. The report concludes with a number of acknowledgements regarding the issues with such policy recommendations, with the most prominent being that the current regulatory framework may prevent some or all of the policies being implemented.

 

The thing to note is that there is certainly no shortage of proposals with regards to what may be done to ‘fix’ the rating arena. If we proceed on the basis that this ‘fix’ is desired, which in certain points I suggest is not actually the case – my forthcoming research on ‘rating addiction’ argues that the system is addicted to ratings quite simply because they fulfil a number of purposes – then the issue is whether such policies are reasonable. A number of the above are reasonable, but some of the above may need a lot of regulatory capital, or better still ‘regulatory will’ to eventually succeed. Whether this ‘will’ exists is, perhaps, truly the question. I have argued in the past, and will no doubt argue in the future, that the real question is ‘who does the current system serve?’ I believe that the answer to this question dictates how much regulation, and by that I mean truly impactful/altering regulation, will be implemented. Partnoy noted in his section that a number of elements of Dodd-Frank have not been adopted – the question then becomes ‘why not?’ If it is because the proposed regulations were not workable within the current regulatory framework, then the issue is that either the legislators are out of touch, or that the framework is not fit for purpose and needs to be changed. Perhaps on the back of these currently proposed policies, the actions of the SEC will be telling.

 

Keywords – CRAs, regulation, @finregmatters


Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Lloyds Bank and the PPI Scandal: The Premature ‘Out of the Woods’ Rhetoric

The Analytical Credit Rating Agency: A New Entrant That Will Further Enhance Russia’s Isolation

The Case of Purdue Pharma, the Sackler Family, and the Opioid Crisis